Slave trade in the United States explained

The internal slave trade in the United States, also known as the domestic slave trade, the Second Middle Passage[1] and the interregional slave trade,[2] was the mercantile trade of enslaved people within the United States. It was most significant after 1808, when the importation of slaves from Africa was prohibited by federal law. Historians estimate that upwards of one million slaves were forcibly relocated from the Upper South, places like Maryland, Virginia, Kentucky, North Carolina, Tennessee, and Missouri, to the territories and then-new states of the Deep South, especially Georgia, Alabama, Louisiana, Mississippi, and Arkansas.

Economists say that transactions in the inter-regional slave market were driven primarily by differences in the marginal productivity of labor, which were based in the relative advantage between climates for the production of staple goods. The trade was strongly influenced by the invention of the cotton gin, which made short-staple cotton profitable for cultivation across large swathes of the upland Deep South (the Black Belt). Previously the commodity was based on long-staple cotton cultivated in coastal areas and the Sea Islands.

The disparity in productivity created arbitrage opportunities for traders to exploit, and it facilitated regional specialization in labor production. Due to a lack of data, particularly with regard to slave prices, land values, and export totals for slaves, the true effects of the domestic slave trade, on both the economy of the Old South and general migration patterns of slaves into southwest territories, remain uncertain. These have served as points of contention among economic historians. The physical effect of forced labor (on remote plantation camps plagued with yellow fever, cholera, and malaria), and social-emotional effect of family separation in American slavery, was nothing short of catastrophic.

History

The history of the domestic slave trade can very clumsily be divided into three major periods:

End of the slave trade

The domestic slave trade wilted during American Civil War—there was a measurable price drop between 1860 and 1862, due to "market uncertainty" discouraging speculators. In May 1861, a "Southern Mississippian" who seemed to oppose secession even though "no man in Mississippi has a larger proportion of his property in negroes" wrote the Louisville Courier that "The secessionists are carrying out the principles and wishes of the abolitionists. Likely negroes could not be sold here at $500 in good money. Negro traders are as scarce here as in Boston."[9] Still, the business remained brisk and prices rose in the protected interior of the CSA, and according to historian Robert Colby, "Confederates nevertheless interpreted the health of the slave trade as embodying that of their nation."

Times got still harder for traders when the Union blockade and total U.S. military control of the Mississippi River prevented the trafficking of people from, say, rural Missouri to New Orleans.[10] But the slave trade, as an integral part of slavery, persisted throughout Confederate-controlled territory until very nearly the end of the war. Ziba B. Oakes was still listing slaves in Charleston, South Carolina newspaper ads on November 1864.[11] A handful of American-flagged ships were still moving enslaved people from Africa to Cuba and Brazil until 1867, when American participation in the slave trade ended once and for all.

Economics

Slavery was a massive element of the U.S. national economy and even more so the economy of the South: "In 1860, enslaved people were worth more than $3 billion (~$ in) to their owners. In today's economy, that would be equivalent to $12.1 trillion or 67 percent of the 2015 U.S. gross domestic product...The unpaid fruits of their labors created an interest so strong that between 1861 and 1865, Confederate leaders staked hundreds of thousands of lives and the future of their civilization on it."[12] As told by historian Frederic Bancroft, "Slave trading was considered a sign of enterprise and prosperity."

The internal slave trade among colonies emerged in 1760 as a source of labor in early America.[13] It is estimated that between 1790 and 1860 approximately 835,000 slaves were relocated to the American South.[14]

The biggest sources for the domestic slave trade were "exporting" states in the Upper South, especially Virginia and Maryland, and as well as Kentucky, North Carolina, Tennessee, and Missouri.[15] From these states most slaves were imported into the Deep South, to the "slave-consuming states," especially Georgia, Alabama, Mississippi, and Louisiana.[16] Robert Fogel and Stanley Engerman attribute the larger proportion of the slave migration due to planters who relocated their entire slave populations to the Deep South to develop new plantations or take over existing ones. Walter Johnson disagrees, finding that only one-third of the population movement south was due to wholesale relocation of slave owner and chattel, while the other two-thirds of the shift was due to the commerce in slaves.[17]

Contributing factors

Soil exhaustion and crop changes

Historians who argue in favor of soil exhaustion as an explanation for slave importation into the Deep South posit that exporting states emerged as slave producers because of the transformation of agriculture in the Upper South. By the late 18th century, the coastal and Piedmont tobacco areas were being converted to mixed crops because of soil exhaustion and changing markets. Because of the deterioration of soil and an increase in demand for food products, states in the upper South shifted crop emphasis from tobacco to grain, which required less labor. This decreased demand left states in the Upper South with an excess supply of labor.

Land availability from Indian removal

With the forced Indian removal by the US making new lands available in the Deep South, there was much higher demand there for workers to cultivate the labor-intensive sugar cane and cotton crops. The extensive development of cotton plantations created the highest demand for labor in the Deep South.[18] [19]

Cotton gin

At the same time, the invention of the cotton gin in the late 18th century transformed short-staple cotton into a profitable crop that could be grown inland in the Deep South. Settlers pushed into the South, expelling the Five Civilized Tribes and other Native American groups. The cotton market had previously been dominated by the long-staple cotton cultivated primarily on the Sea Islands and in the coastal South Carolina Lowcountry. The consequent boom in the cotton industry, coupled with the labor-intensive nature of the crop, created a need for slave labor in the Deep South that could be satisfied by excess supply further north.

The increased demand for labor in the Deep South pushed up the price of slaves in markets such as New Orleans, which became the fourth-largest city in the country based in part on profits from the slave trade and related businesses. The price differences between the Upper and Deep South created demand. Slave traders took advantage of this arbitrage opportunity by buying at lower prices in the Upper South and then selling slaves at a profit after taking or transporting them further south. Some scholars believe there was an increasing prevalence in the Upper South of "breeding" slaves for export. The proven reproductive capacity of enslaved women was advertised as selling point and a feature that increased value.

Resolve financial deficits

Although not as significant as the exportation of slaves to Deep South, farmers and land owners who needed to pay off loans increasingly used slaves as a cash substitute. This had also contributed to the growth of the internal slave trade.

Statistics

Economic historians have offered estimates for the annual revenue generated by the inter-regional slave trade for exporters that range from $3.75 to $6.7 million.

The demand for prime-aged slaves, from the ages of 15 to 30, accounted for 70 percent of the slave population relocated to the Deep South. Since the ages of slaves were often unknown by the traders themselves, physical attributes such as height often dictated demand in order to minimize asymmetric information.

Robert Fogel and Stanley Engerman estimated that the slave trade accounted for 16 percent of the relocation of enslaved African Americans, in their work Time on the Cross. This estimate, however, was severely criticized for the extreme sensitivity of the linear function used to gather this approximation.[20] A more recent estimate, given by Jonathan B. Pritchett, has this figure at about 50 percent, or about 835,000 slaves total between 1790 and 1850. Without the inter-regional slave trade, it is possible that forced migration of slaves would have occurred naturally due to natural population pressures and the subsequent increase in land prices. In 1965, William L. Miller contended that, "it is even doubtful whether the interstate slave traffic made a net contribution to the westward flow of the population."

Importation, piracy, and interstate kidnapping

The transatlantic slave trade was not prohibited under federal law until 1808. Imports from Africa to Southern states were ongoing from 1776 until that time, most often through the ports of Charleston and Savannah. Post-1808 importation of slaves to the United States from the Caribbean, South America, and Africa was illegal but piracy continued until the opening of the American Civil War.

Kidnapping into slavery in the United States was an ongoing issue. Unaccompanied children and people of color traveling to port cities and border states were particularly vulnerable. There are multiple accounts of armed gangs breaking into the homes of free people in the dead of night and carrying away whole families. The lucky ones were sometimes redeemed from the local slave jail by friends or lawyers before they were shipped south.

Breeding of slave children for sale

See main article: Slave breeding in the United States. According to Frederic Bancroft in Slave-Trading in the Old South (1931) young female slaves were also considered an excellent financial investment: "Not only real estate, but also stocks, bonds and all other personal property were little prized in comparison with slaves...Absurd as it now seems, slaves, especially girls and young women, because of prospective increase, were considered the best investment for persons of small means."

Profits

Irish economic theorist John Elliot Cairnes suggested in his work The Slave Power that the inter-regional slave trade was a major component in ensuring the economic vitality of the Old South. Many economic historians, however, have since refuted the validity of this point. The general consensus seems to support Professor William L. Miller's claim that the inter-regional slave trade "did not provide the major part of the income of planters in the older states during any period."

The returns gained by traders from the sale price of slaves were offset by both the fall in the value of land, that resulted from the subsequent decrease in the marginal productivity of land, and the fall in the price of output, which occurred due to the increase in market size as given by westward expansion.[21] Kotlikoff suggested that the net effect of the inter-regional slave trade on the economy of the Old South was negligible, if not negative.[21]

The profits realized through the sale and shipment of enslaved people were in turn reinvested in banking, railroads, and even colleges. A striking example of the connection between the domestic slave trade and higher education can be found in the 1838 sale of 272 slaves by the Maryland Jesuits to Louisiana; a small portion of the proceeds of the sale was used to pay down the debts of Georgetown College.[22] Caroline Donovan endowed a chair at Johns Hopkins in 1889 using part of the fortune accumulated by her late husband, Baltimore trader Joseph S. Donovan.[23]

Markets and traders

See main article: Slave markets and slave jails in the United States and List of slave traders of the United States. In their day, slave traders were called everything from broker, the generic term favored in Charleston, to nigger-trader (sometimes transcribed as niggah-tradah),[24] a term that appears in both slave traders' own descriptions of themselves in oral interviews and in records of African-American folk music of the era. Negro trader, negro speculator, and slave dealer were common occupational titles that appeared in census records and city directories. Anti-slavery activists called them soul drivers.[25] Slaves sometimes spoke of the Georgia-man who would take them away to, if not the geographical Georgia, a proverbial "Georgia," elsewhere in the cotton and sugar lands far south from where they were raised.[26]

In the earliest years of the market, "dozens of independent speculators...bought lots of ten or so slaves, generally on credit, in Upper-South states like Virginia and Maryland."[27] In 1836 a Philadelphia paper characterized the work of negro brokers: "They conceive the business of pawn brokers and merchandize brokers. They lend money on the security of slaves, taking the latter as a pledge, to be sold if the pledge be not redeemed. They advance cash on slaves to be sold at auction or private sale, deducting from the proceeds of sale their commission and expenses. They buy and sell slaves upon commission, to suit their customers, and sometimes doubtless, buy and sell free people of color on pretence of their being slaves."[28]

The argument has been made that the domestic slave trade was one that resulted in "superprofits" for traders. But Jonathan Pritchett points to evidence that there were a significant number of firms engaged in the market, a relatively dense concentration of these firms, and low barriers to entry. He says that traders who were exporting slaves from the Upper South were price-taking, profit-maximizers acting in a market that achieved a long-run competitive equilibrium.

Using an admittedly limited set of data from Dunning School historian Ulrich Phillips (includes market data from Richmond, Charleston, mid-Georgia, and Louisiana), Robert Evans Jr. estimates that the average differential between slave prices in the Upper South and Deep South markets from 1830–1835 was $232.[29] In 1876, Tarlton Arterburn told a newspaper reporter that they'd made an average profit of 30 to 40 percent "per head".[30]

Evans suggests that interstate slave traders earned a wage greater than that of an alternative profession in skilled mechanical trades.[29] However, if slave traders possessed skills similar to those used in supervisory mechanics (e.g. skills used by a chief engineer), then slave traders received an income that was not greater than the one they would have received had they entered in an alternative profession.[29] In addition to full-time traders, so-called tavern traders worked on a small scale, especially in the first quarter of the 19th century, examples being the slave auctions held at Garland Burnett's tavern in Baltimore,[31] Washington Robey's slave pen and tavern in Washington, D.C.,[32] Turner Brashears of Brashears' Stand along the Natchez Trace,[33] as well as the notorious Patty Cannon ring in Delaware.

Chesapeake cities like Baltimore, Alexandria, Washington, D.C., and Richmond were "slave collecting and resale centers."[34] Major slave-buying markets were located Charleston, Savannah, Memphis, and above all, New Orleans.[35] Economists estimate that more than 135,000 enslaved people were sold in New Orleans between 1804 and 1862.[36] Some traders only bought and sold locally; smaller interstate trading companies would typically have both upper south and lower south locations, for buying and selling, respectively. Larger interstate firms, like Franklin & Armfield, and Bolton, Dickens & Co., might have locations or traders under contract in a dozen cities. Dealers in the upper south worked to collect what they called "shipping lots"—enough people to be worth spending time and money arranging for their transport south.[37] There was a trading season, namely winter and spring, because summer and autumn were planting and harvesting time; farmers and plantation owners generally would not buy or sell until that year's crop was in. The seasonality of the trade is visible in the record books of Missouri trader John R. White, which show that "Over 90 percent of the slaves imported to New Orleans were sold in the six months between November and April."

The notion that slave traders were social outcasts of low reputation, even in the South, was initially promulgated by defensive southerners and later by figures like historian Ulrich B. Phillips.[38] Historian Frederic Bancroft, author of Slave-Trading in the Old South (1931) found—to the contrary of Phillips' position—that many traders were esteemed members of their communities.[39] Contemporary researcher Steven Deyle argues that the "trader's position in society was not unproblematic and owners who dealt with the trader felt the need to satisfy themselves that they acted honorably," while Michael Tadman contends that "'trader as outcast' operated at the level of propaganda" whereas white slave owners almost universally professed a belief that slaves were not human like them, and thus dismissed the consequences of slave trading as beneath consideration. Similarly, historian Charles Dew read hundreds of letters to slave traders and found virtually zero narrative evidence for guilt, shame, or contrition about the slave trade: "If you begin with the absolute belief in white supremacy—unquestioned white superiority/unquestioned black inferiority—everything falls neatly into place: the African is inferior racial 'stock,' living in sin and ignorance and barbarism and heathenism on the 'Dark Continent' until enslaved...Slavery thus miraculously becomes a form of 'uplift' for this supposedly benighted and brutish race of people. And once notions of white supremacy and black inferiority are in place in the American South, they are passed on from one generation to the next with all the certainty and inevitability of a genetic trait." And yet despite the dehumanizing doctrines of white supremacy that seemingly mandated separatism and black oppression, there is evidence that at least some slave traders were perfectly capable of recognizing enslaved people as human, rather than some form of livestock: a not-insignificant number of white slave traders provided for the families of mixed-raced children they'd formed with women they'd once enslaved,[40] multiple sources attest that Baltimore slave trader James F. Purvis quit the human-trafficking business and devoted himself to banking and charity projects after a religious conversion,[41] and New Orleans trader Elihu Creswell emancipated his 51 slaves upon his death and even funded their transportation to free states.[42] As historian Deyle put it in Carry Me Back (2005): "While there is no record of any slave traders feeling guilt over what they did for a living, the actions taken by the New Orleans dealer Elihu Creswell do raise some questions."[43]

Harriet Beecher Stowe commented on slave traders in A Key to Uncle Tom's Cabin (1853), in reference to her fictional character Mr. Haley:

Product and price

Male slaves were worth more than female slaves; one study found that on average males sold for nine percent more than females. But female slaves came with "increase"—children born enslaved to an enslaved woman were saleable, thus providing excellent return on investment.[44] Prime age slaves were those ages 10 to 35, or more broadly enslaved children older than eight and enslaved adults younger than 40, because people of those ages were presumed to be able work and/or reproduce for an extended period of time.[45] Overall, buyers competed most for male field hands aged 18 to 30, so "the selling price of this class supplied something of a basis for the sale of all Negroes". As a rule, there was an inverse correlation between age and price for enslaved people over 40. For example, in 1835 South Carolina, when Ann Ball spent almost to buy 215 enslaved people from the estates of her deceased relatives, she made a point to buy several apparently elderly slaves (Old Rachel, Old Lucy, Old Charles) and the lowest-priced single person was Old Peg, purchased for, compared to an average price of $371 per.[46] [47] Another illustration of comparative slave prices is from the District of Columbia Compensated Emancipation program: "The highest priced slave was a blacksmith worth $1800, and the lowest [priced was] a two-months-old mulatto baby, worth $25."[48] On the other end of the price spectrum from old women and babies is the amount men would pay for sexual access to physically attractive young female slaves, the so-called "fancy girls," such as was the case is this post-war boast by former slave trader Jack Campbell: "Long as you ask about it, I remember the biggest money I ever got for a nigger was $9,000 for a devilish pretty quadroon wench that I sold in Louisville, about '52 or '53. She was only 18, and was about as white as you or me, and her two children had light, curly hair. Her master lived down near Bowling Green, and though he didn't want to part with her he was so down on his luck that he had to sell her. I heard, too, that his wife swore that nigger must leave the plantation or she would go home to her family. My instructions were not to take less than $6,000 for the girl, and I was to get a big percentage on all over that, so when they put her on the block I talked her up for all she was worth...There was more than twenty men bidding for her, and the fellow that got her for $9,000 was a rich and gay young bachelor from Tennessee, who happened to be in the city on a spree and was attracted by curiosity to the sale. He was a little drinky and wasn't caring anything for his ducats. He was so set on having the girl, I believe he would have given $20,000 for her if anybody had bid her up that high. He carried her home that day, and I ain't going to tell you anything more about him than that he made a big name in the Southern army and was killed at the head of his soldiers. One of this woman's children by her first master lives in a Massachusetts town now and is a rich man. There isn't a sign of black blood in him."[49] The amount $9,000 in 1853 would be over $250,000 today.

There were several broad categories of work for which enslaved people were purchased: agriculture, domestic service, mechanical, and commercial-industrial. Agricultural workers grew and processed cash crops like cotton and sugar, or managed herds of cattle in Texas, etc. Domestics worked in the household or in hotels and taverns, cooking, cleaning, laundering clothes, producing household goods, and providing childcare, including supplying the free white babies they cared for with their own human milk. Mechanics were expensive and prized: these were the smiths, builders, craftsmen, etc. Finally, commercial-industrial slaves were put to work all over the south in ironworks, steamboat boiler rooms, on railroads, at gin-houses, bagasse-burners, lumber mills, turpentine stills, and so forth. The owner of a slave might or might not be a slave's employer: owners often rented, leased, or "hired out" their slaves.

According to historian Bancroft, in the great slave market that was New Orleans, enslaved people imported from Virginia, and to a lesser extent Maryland and South Carolina, were advertised as an especially desirable product, whereas "the many slaves brought from Missouri and Kentucky" were rarely advertised by their place of origin. "Acclimated" slaves known to be immune to yellow fever and other communicable diseases also commanded a premium.[50]

According to economist Laurence Kotlikoff, as the American Civil War was beginning in 1861, the typical price of a prime-age male slave sold in New Orleans was . On average the prices for light-skinned female slaves were 5.4 percent higher than the prices for darker-skinned female slaves, possibly indicating colorism and sexual attraction as a factor in a market dominated by male buyers.[51] Per Kotlikoff's calculations, "Throughout the ante-bellum 1800s, positive premia were paid for males, skilled slaves, slaves with guarantees, and children sold with their mothers."

Routes

There were four main methods of forced transportation of the enslaved. Initially, transport was either on foot or by sailing ship, but following the popularization of the railroad and the steamboat in the 1840s, both were commonly used.

Specific routes

Combining modes was also common, for example, as reported in the Anti-Slavery Bugle in 1849:[59]

Law

In the early 19th century several slave states had unenforced statutes prohibiting the interstate slave trade in hopes of minimizing the increase of black populations within those states. These laws were undermined in many ways; for example, "Hamburg, South Carolina was built up just opposite Augusta, for the purpose of furnishing slaves to the planters of Georgia. Augusta is the market to which the planters of Upper and Middle Georgia bring their cotton; and if they want to purchase negroes, they step over into Hamburg and do so. There are two large houses there, with piazzas in front to expose the 'chattels' to the public during the day, and yards in rear of them where they are penned up at night like sheep, so close that they can hardly breathe, with bull-dogs on the outside as sentinels. They sometimes have thousands here for sale, who in consequence of their number suffer most horribly."[60] Similarly, in Alabama, a historian explained in 1845 that a ban had been undermined to the point that it was ultimately abandoned entirely: "...The people of Alabama at one time became alarmed at the evils which they properly anticipated would grow out of this traffic. Their Legislators enacted laws against it, and for a short time they exercised salutary restraints; but soon they were evaded. The Creek Nation was then an Indian Territory, under the jurisdiction of the General Government, lying immediately on our eastern border. Here Negro Traders sought a shield for their operations, and our citizens went there to make purchases. Worn out at last with such subterfuges and shifts, the Legislature repealed this restrictive law..."[61] When Louisiana banned slave traders from out of state in 1832, Austin Woolfolk set up operations at Fort Adams, Mississippi, which was the first steamboat landing beyond the state line.[62]

Bans on interstate slave trading
State Notes
Alabama Limitations on interstate slave trading passed 1832[63]
DelawareBanned imports and exports of slaves at statehood (1787)[64]
KentuckyNon-Importation Act passed 1833,[65] repealed 1849[66]
Louisiana Imports banned 1826–1828;[67] "...slavers circumvented rules like Louisiana's strict requirement that captives entering the state bear certificates of good character by manufacturing fake certificates."
Georgia Imports banned 1788, repealed in 1856[68]
Mississippi Banned in 1832 state constitution, never enforced, although there was 1837 legislation and case law about the issue (Groves v. Slaughter, Rowan v. Runnels, Hickman v. Rose).[69] [70] [71] One news report in 1840 claimed that Mississippi slave owners had outstanding debts to slave traders totaling approximately .[72]
Tennessee Banned 1827–1855; unenforced

See also

Sources

Further reading

See main article: Bibliography of the slave trade in the United States.

External links

Notes and References

  1. Web site: What Was the 2nd Middle Passage?. Henry Louis Jr. . Gates. 28 January 2013 .
  2. Web site: History Engine: Tools for Collaborative Education and Research – Episodes. Digital Scholarship. Lab. historyengine.richmond.edu.
  3. Web site: Slavery . 2024-01-08 . NCpedia.org.
  4. Web site: Marques . Leonardo . The United States and the Transatlantic Slave Trade to the Americas, 1776–1867 . 2024-01-08 . etd.library.emory.edu . 44 . English . Dissertation later published by Yale UP.
  5. Shugerman . Jed Handelsman . 2002 . The Louisiana Purchase and South Carolina's Reopening of the Slave Trade in 1803 . Journal of the Early Republic . 22 . 2 . 263–290 . 10.2307/3125182 . 0275-1275.
  6. Book: James, D. Clayton . Antebellum Natchez . 1993 . Louisiana State University Press . 978-0-8071-1860-3 . Baton Rouge, Louisiana . 197 . en-us . 68028496 . 28281641 . 1968.
  7. Kendall . John S. . January 1939 . Shadow Over the City . The Louisiana Historical Quarterly . New Orleans . . 22 . 1 . 142–165 . 0095-5949 . 1782268 . LDS Film 1425689, Image Group Number (DGS) 1640025 . FamilySearch Digital Library.
  8. Web site: Dickey . J.D. . 2022-03-01 . The Tormented Rise of Abolition in 1830’s America . 2024-05-10 . TIME . en.
  9. News: 1861-05-27 . A Letter from Mississippi . 2024-01-12 . The Courier-Journal . 3.
  10. Web site: Henry Clay Bruce, 1836-1902. The New Man. Twenty-Nine Years a Slave. Twenty-Nine Years a Free Man. . 2023-12-13 . docsouth.unc.edu . 102–103.
  11. News: 1864-11-09 . Superior Male Cook, at Private Sale . 2023-07-19 . The Charleston Mercury . 2.
  12. Book: Schermerhorn, Calvin . Remembering the Memphis Massacre: An American Story . University of Georgia Press . 2020 . 9780820356495 . Bond . Beverly Greene . Chapter 2: 'Cash for Slaves' The African American Trail of Tears . O'Donovan . Susan Eva.
  13. Web site: Domestic Slave Trade. In Motion. 1 March 2011. 12 June 2018. https://web.archive.org/web/20180612140023/http://www.inmotionaame.org/migrations/topic.cfm?migration=3&topic=1&tab=image. dead.
  14. Pritchett. Jonathan B.. Quantitative Estimates of the United States Interregional Slave Trade, 1820–1860. The Journal of Economic History. June 2001. 61. 2. 467–475. 2698028. 10.1017/S002205070102808X. 154462144 .
  15. Web site: A key to Uncle Tom's cabin; presenting the original facts and documents upon which the story is founded. Together with corroborative statements verifying ... . 2023-08-25 . HathiTrust . 351 . 2027/uiug.30112003184378?urlappend=%3Bseq=365 . en.
  16. Jonathan B. Pritchett . The Domestic United States Slave Trade: New Evidence. Journal of Interdisciplinary History. Winter 1991. 21. 3. 447–477. 204955. 10.2307/204955. Freudenberger. Herman.
  17. Book: Johnson, Walter . Soul by Soul: Life Inside the Antebellum Slave Market . Harvard University Press . 2009 . 9780674039155 . Cambridge . 5 (migration cause), 48 (interstate firms), 49 (seasonality), 50 (transportation) . en-us . 923120203 . Walter Johnson (historian).
  18. Deyle. Steven. The Irony of Liberty: Origins of the Domestic Slave Trade. Journal of the Early Republic. Spring 1992. 12. 1. 37–62. 3123975. 10.2307/3123975.
  19. Pritchett. Jonathan B.. The Interregional Slave Trade and the Selection of Slaves for the New Orleans Market. Journal of Interdisciplinary History. Summer 1997. 28. 1. 57–85. 206166. 10.2307/206166.
  20. Carstensen. F.V.. S.E. Goodman. Trouble on the Auction Block: Interregional Slave Sales and the Reliability of a Linear Equation. Journal of Interdisciplinary History. Autumn 1977. 8. 2. 315–318. 202791. 10.2307/202791. 2.
  21. Kotlikoff. Laurence J.. Sebastian Pinera. The Journal of Economic History. June 1977. 37. 2. 434–450. 2118765. 10.1017/S002205070009700X. The Old South's Stake in the Inter-Regional Movement of Slaves, 1850–1860. 2. 153416059 .
  22. Book: Curran, Robert. A History of Georgetown University: From Academy to University, 1789–1889. Georgetown University Press. 2010. 978-1-58901-688-0. Washington, DC. 129–130.
  23. Web site: Hub staff report . 2023-10-11 . Name Review Board makes first de-naming recommendation, refines processes . 2024-01-08 . The Hub . en.
    • Book: Coleman, J. Winston . Slavery times in Kentucky . University of North Carolina Press . 1940 . Chapel Hill, N.C. . 142–217 . en-us . Chapter VI: 'Niggah Tradahs' & Chapter VII: Down the River & Chapter VIII: 'Nigger Stealers' .
  24. News: 1851-03-22 . Another Soul-Driver Gone . 2024-06-26 . Anti-Slavery Bugle . 1.
  25. Web site: Sanders . J. Chris . The Half I'm a 'Georgia-man' . 2024-06-29 . The Courier-Journal . en-US.
  26. Book: Johnson, Walter . River of Dark Dreams: Slavery and Empire in the Cotton Kingdom . Belknap Press of Harvard University Press . 2013 . 9780674074880 . Cambridge, Mass. . 41 (early years, 10 at a time) . en-us . 2012030065 . 827947225 . Walter Johnson (historian).
  27. News: 1836-10-19 . New Species of Brokers . 2 . Public Ledger . Philadelphia . 2023-08-15.
  28. Evans Jr.. Robert. Some Economic Aspects of the Domestic Slave Trade, 1830–1860. Southern Economic Journal. April 1961. 27. 4. 329–337. 1055531. 10.2307/1055531.
  29. News: 1876-06-03 . A Reminder of Slavery Days . 2024-06-26 . Martinez News-Gazette . 4.
  30. Web site: 2022-05-04 . Photographs by Amy Davis . Seeing the Unseen: Baltimore's slave trade . 2023-10-08 . Baltimore Sun.
  31. 1950 . Slavery and the Slave Trade in the District of Columbia . Negro History Bulletin . 14 . 1 . 7–18 . 44212391 . 0028-2529.
  32. Web site: Brashears Stand and Old Trace, Milepost 104.5 (U.S. National Park Service) . 2023-10-08 . www.nps.gov . en.
  33. McInnis . Maurie D. . Maurie D. McInnis . Fall 2013 . Mapping the slave trade in Richmond and New Orleans . Building & Landscapes . 20 . 2 . 102–125 . 10.5749/buildland.20.2.0102 . 10.5749/buildland.20.2.0102 . 160472953 . registration.
  34. Book: Bancroft, Frederic . Frederic Bancroft . . University of South Carolina Press . Introduction by Michael Tadman . 2023 . 978-1-64336-427-8 . Southern Classics Series . 173 (broker), 295 (enterprise and prosperity), 316 (VA premium), 343 (young girls) . en-us . 1931.
  35. Kotlikoff . Laurence J. . October 1979 . THE STRUCTURE OF SLAVE PRICES IN NEW ORLEANS, 1804 TO 1862 . Economic Inquiry . en . 17 . 4 . 496–518 . 10.1111/j.1465-7295.1979.tb00544.x.
  36. Book: Dew, Charles B. . The making of a racist : a southerner reflects on family, history, and the slave trade . University of Virginia Press . 2016 . 9780813938882 . Charlottesville . 111 (shipping lots), 154 (racism) . en-us . 2015043815.
  37. Book: Tadman, Michael . Internal Slave Trades . 2012-09-18 . Oxford University Press . Smith . Mark M. . 1 . en . 10.1093/oxfordhb/9780199227990.013.0029 . Paquette . Robert L..
  38. April 1931 . Frederic Bancroft, Slave-Trading in the Old South . The Journal of Negro History . en . 16 . 2 . 240–241 . 10.2307/2714086 . 2714086 . 153885388 . 0022-2992.
  39. Book: Finley, Alexandra J. . An Intimate Economy: Enslaved Women, Work, and America's Domestic Slave Trade . University of North Carolina Press . 2020 . 9781469655123 . Chapel Hill, N.C. . en-us . 10.5149/9781469655130_finley . 2019052078 . 1194871275 . .
  40. News: Beale . Solon . 1855-08-22 . Wheeler & Lynde . The Slave Prisons of Baltimore . 2024-01-02 . Bangor Daily Whig and Courier . Bangor, Maine . 2 . XXII . 44.
  41. Kranz . Rachel . 2008 . Capturing Creswell . Women's Studies Quarterly . 36 . 1/2 . 214–220 . 0732-1562.
  42. Book: Deyle, Steven H. . Carry Me Back: The Domestic Slave Trade in American Life . Oxford University Press . 2005 . 978-0195160406 . New York . en-us . 2004056840 . 61342034 . 7390529M. Page 241
  43. Bancroft p. 343
  44. Johnson, River of Dark Dreams, p 159
  45. Web site: Hawes . Jennifer Berry . 2023-06-16 . How a Grad Student Uncovered the Largest Known Slave Auction in the U.S. . 2024-01-03 . ProPublica . en.
  46. Davila . Lauren . Public Memory of the Domestic Slave Trade in Charleston, South Carolina . College of Charleston . 2023 . .
  47. Mitchell . Mary . 1963 . "I Held George Washington's Horse": Compensated Emancipation in the District of Columbia . Records of the Columbia Historical Society, Washington, D.C. . 63/65 . 221–229 . 0897-9049.
  48. News: n.a. . 1884-05-24 . The Last of His Kind: Talk with an Old Slave-Seller Who Lags Superfluous on the Stage . 2023-08-18 . St. Louis Globe-Democrat . St. Louis, Mo. . 12 . en-us.
  49. Book: Olivarius, Kathryn . Necropolis: Disease, Power, and Capitalism in the Cotton Kingdom . 2022-04-19 . Belknap Press . 978-0-674-24105-3 . Cambridge, MA.
  50. Bancroft p. 328–329
  51. Williams . Jennie K. . 2020-04-02 . Trouble the water: The Baltimore to New Orleans coastwise slave trade, 1820–1860 . Slavery & Abolition . en . 41 . 2 . 275–303 . 10.1080/0144039X.2019.1660509 . 0144-039X.
  52. Web site: Railroads and the Making of Modern America . 2023-01-06 . railroads.unl.edu.
  53. Parr . Elizabeth L. . January 1928 . Digitization sponsored by Joan & Burlyn Pike . Kentucky's Overland Trade with the Ante-Bellum South . Filson Club Quarterly . Louisville, Kentucky . Filson Historical Society . II . 71–81 . 0015-1874 . 6674913.
  54. Book: Daniels, Jonathan . The devil's backbone : the story of the Natchez Trace . 1971 . New York : McGraw-Hill . Internet Archive . 978-0-07-015306-6 . 107 . en-us.
  55. Book: Nolen, Claude H. . African American Southerners in Slavery, Civil War and Reconstruction . 2005-08-29 . McFarland . 978-0-7864-2451-1 . 62 . en.
  56. Clark . T. D. . December 1934 . The Slave Trade between Kentucky and the Cotton Kingdom . The Mississippi Valley Historical Review . 21 . 3 . 331–342 . 10.2307/1897378 . 1897378.
  57. Stokes . Rebecca Martin . History of Grenada (1830–1880) . 1929 . Master's . No. 1972 . University of Mississippi . Oxford, Miss. .
  58. News: 1849-07-06 . Slavery in the District . 2024-06-02 . Anti-Slavery Bugle . 1.
  59. News: 1848-10-27 . Slave Trading in Georgia . 3 . Anti-Slavery Bugle . 2023-08-15.
  60. News: Pickett . Albert . Albert J. Pickett . 1845-10-02 . A Letter from Col. Albert Pickett . 2 . Advertiser and Register . 2023-08-14.
  61. Calderhead . William . 1977 . The Role of the Professional Slave Trader in a Slave Economy: Austin Woolfolk, A Case Study . Civil War History . en . 23 . 3 . 195–211 . 10.1353/cwh.1977.0041 . 1533-6271 . 143907436.
  62. Book: Jewett . Clayton E. . Slavery in the South: a state-by-state history . Allen . John O. . 2004 . Greenwood Press . 978-0-313-32019-4 . Westport, Conn. . 1 . en-US.
  63. Book: Jewett . Clayton E. . Slavery in the South: A State-by-State History . Allen . John O. . 2004-02-28 . Greenwood Publishing Group . 978-0-313-32019-4 . 35 . en.
  64. McDougle . Ivan E. . 1918 . The Development of Slavery . The Journal of Negro History . 3 . 3 . 214–239 . 10.2307/2713409 . 2713409 . 149804505 . 0022-2992.
  65. Clark . T. D. . December 1934 . The Slave Trade between Kentucky and the Cotton Kingdom . The Mississippi Valley Historical Review . 21 . 3 . 331 . 10.2307/1897378.
  66. Book: Rothman, Joshua D. . The Ledger and the Chain: How Domestic Slave Traders Shaped America . Basic Books . 2021 . 9781541616592 . 118 . en-us . 2020038845.
  67. Web site: Slave Laws of Georgia, 1755–1860 . 2023-07-18 . georgiaarchives.org.
  68. Book: Myers, Gustavus . History of the Supreme Court of the United States . 1912 . C. H. Kerr . 400–403 . en.
  69. Web site: Groves v. Slaughter, 40 U.S. 449 (1841) . Justia Law . en.
  70. Web site: Rowan v. Runnels, 46 U.S. 134 (1847) . 2024-07-05 . Justia Law . en.
  71. News: 1840-02-08 . Slave property . 2024-08-03 . The Daily Selma Reporter . 2.